The case for and against by Sol Picciotto and Miles Dean respectively
Miles Dean
Founder, Milestone International Tax Partners
Practical difficulties make implementing unitary taxation a pipe dream. The economic effects for the UK are far from clear.
Unitary taxation has been touted as a panacea to the current issue of multinational tax avoidance. Advocates say that such a system produces a more equitable result on the basis one can fairly allocate global profits according to an agreed formula which takes account of where the economic activity occurs. This is a fallacy for two main reasons. First, and most significantly, is that the practical difficulties in implementing such a system make the concept of unitary taxation little more than a pipe dream. There are three critical elements to any unitary taxation system that would need to be adopted consistently on a global basis:
The first two elements might conceivably be agreed on a global basis (for example, based on a modified version of international accounting standards). However, it is inconceivable that a global consensus could emerge as to how global profits should be allocated between jurisdictions. For example, a highly developed economy might favour a formula that gives preference to payroll costs. On the other hand, a developing economy might give preference to an allocation factor that favours headcount. The point is that each jurisdiction will develop own formula that maximises their share of the global profit. The result (absent an entirely new framework of tax treaties) will be double taxation which in turn will diminish economic growth and magnify unemployment.
Secondly, the economic effects of the UK moving to a system of unitary taxation system are far from clear. Margaret Hodge and the ‘kangaroo court’ that is the PAC to advocate a unitary system of taxation with an allocation factor based on sales because, in their simplistic view, this would increase the corporation tax take from multinationals such as Amazon. However, a allocation factor is likely to significantly reduce the UK’s corporation tax take from UK based multinationals, such as Rolls Royce and the pharmaceutical companies, which generate significant overseas sales based on UK activities. Until the economic impact of a unitary system has been properly evaluated the case for unitary taxation is far from clear.
And finally, one might observe that the EU has for many years been attempting to impose unitary taxation in the form of a Trojan horse that is the common consolidated tax base. The fact that this project has not gone further than the drawing board despite years of consultation highlights the practical difficulties of designing and implementing a unitary system. The growing instability in the eurozone highlights the potentially dangerous implications of ceding further sovereignty over the UK’s tax system.
The case for and against by Sol Picciotto and Miles Dean respectively
Miles Dean
Founder, Milestone International Tax Partners
Practical difficulties make implementing unitary taxation a pipe dream. The economic effects for the UK are far from clear.
Unitary taxation has been touted as a panacea to the current issue of multinational tax avoidance. Advocates say that such a system produces a more equitable result on the basis one can fairly allocate global profits according to an agreed formula which takes account of where the economic activity occurs. This is a fallacy for two main reasons. First, and most significantly, is that the practical difficulties in implementing such a system make the concept of unitary taxation little more than a pipe dream. There are three critical elements to any unitary taxation system that would need to be adopted consistently on a global basis:
The first two elements might conceivably be agreed on a global basis (for example, based on a modified version of international accounting standards). However, it is inconceivable that a global consensus could emerge as to how global profits should be allocated between jurisdictions. For example, a highly developed economy might favour a formula that gives preference to payroll costs. On the other hand, a developing economy might give preference to an allocation factor that favours headcount. The point is that each jurisdiction will develop own formula that maximises their share of the global profit. The result (absent an entirely new framework of tax treaties) will be double taxation which in turn will diminish economic growth and magnify unemployment.
Secondly, the economic effects of the UK moving to a system of unitary taxation system are far from clear. Margaret Hodge and the ‘kangaroo court’ that is the PAC to advocate a unitary system of taxation with an allocation factor based on sales because, in their simplistic view, this would increase the corporation tax take from multinationals such as Amazon. However, a allocation factor is likely to significantly reduce the UK’s corporation tax take from UK based multinationals, such as Rolls Royce and the pharmaceutical companies, which generate significant overseas sales based on UK activities. Until the economic impact of a unitary system has been properly evaluated the case for unitary taxation is far from clear.
And finally, one might observe that the EU has for many years been attempting to impose unitary taxation in the form of a Trojan horse that is the common consolidated tax base. The fact that this project has not gone further than the drawing board despite years of consultation highlights the practical difficulties of designing and implementing a unitary system. The growing instability in the eurozone highlights the potentially dangerous implications of ceding further sovereignty over the UK’s tax system.